Page 144 - Critical Political Economy of the Media
P. 144

Political economy of the Internet  123

             assessments of the relative paucity of new ‘mass media’ providers must be balanced by
             acknowledging the diversification of content creation today, the enormous expansion
             of publication and online communication by organisations, and professional–
             amateur content creation and communication (Fuchs 2008). As van der Wurff
             (2008) and Benkler (2006) examine, there has been an enormous expansion in
             content distributed free by non-media organisations and individuals, with motives
             ranging from informing existing or potential customers to advocating causes –
             but not with the aim of making money by selling content or advertisements. Yet
             the resources for publication are greater in the commercial sector, and government,
             than in civil society. The Internet has significantly advanced the erosion of
             boundaries between editorial, marketing communications and transaction activ-
             ities. Conventions to separate editorial and advertising, telling and selling, speech
             and commerce have been established more weakly and unevenly online (Sparks
             2004). This has been amongst the drivers for commercial organisations to invest
             in online publishing and communications, in order to engage directly with
             consumers without media intermediaries, or wholesalers and retailers.


             Incumbent advantages and strategies
             Media conglomerates pursue strategies to seek to maintain dominant market
             positions, through investment, branding, cross-promotion and advertiser rela-
             tionships (McChesney 2004b, 2008), control over gateways to services, efforts to
             control intellectual property, and expanding sources of control through surveillance
             and data mining to track and target users (Turow 2006, 2011). Some of these
             strategies proved unsuccessful but others remain relevant advantages, in particular
             those of branding and marketing (Sinclair 2011). Established media brands have
             proved to be key assets in increasingly competitive and cluttered markets. Brands
             could be extended into new online properties and services. Conglomerates can
             use websites to cross-promote and sell their other products and services. Large
             media companies could exploit their relationships with advertisers, for instance
             offering (or requiring) cross-platform advertising packages. Large corporations
             have greater access to capital than smaller companies and can invest in online
             businesses as a form of research and development, and use their finance capacity to
             seek to outspend rivals and outlast competition. The costs of maintaining Murdoch’s
             short-lived iPad-only publication The Daily were estimated at $2 million per year for
             running costs and promotion alone, requiring 2 per cent of total iPad users in
             the US to subscribe 99 cents per week in order to break even.
               There is support for the ‘new economy’ model advanced in Chris Anderson’s
             Long Tail (2004, 2009). Anderson argues that online inventory overcomes the
             physical and cost constraints of goods displayed on store shelves. Distribution
             costs for digital goods like music, video and information approach zero, allowing
             a long tail of marketable products. Instead of focusing on the ‘head’, the few,
             lucrative blockbuster hits produced by global media corporations, Anderson calls
             attention to the long tail, the expansion of low-volume transactions that are the
   139   140   141   142   143   144   145   146   147   148   149