Page 21 - Cultural Studies and Political Economy
P. 21

10                     Introduction to Part One

           be to influence future cultural productions. As well, cultural “commodities” may af-
           fect indirectly those without direct exposure to the cultural artifact, the very definition
           of an “externality” or third-party effect. These properties make cultural goods ill-
           suited for mainstream economics—one reason among several for preferring political
           economy to neoclassical analyses of media and cultural industries. See Robert E.
           Babe, Communication and the Transformation of Economics (Boulder, CO: Westview
           Press, 1995).
             4. Edward Comor,  Consumption and the Globalization Project: International
           Hegemony and the Annihilation of Time (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2008).
             5. McLuhan described himself as a “disciple” of Innis, and referred to his own
           most scholarly tome, The Gutenberg Galaxy, as but “a footnote to the observations of
           Innis.” James Carey once quipped that the Canadian contribution to media studies
           would have been far more impressive had the Innis-to-McLuhan lineage been in the
           opposite direction. Elsewhere I have argued that McLuhan turned Innis on his head
           by emphasizing biases in reception (eye vs. ear) as opposed to biases in transmission
           (space vs. time), in effect de-politicizing Innis. See Robert E. Babe, Canadian Com-
           munication Thought: Ten Foundational Writers (Toronto: University of Toronto Press,
           2000), chapter 11. See also the discussion at the conclusion of chapter 7 regarding the
           integration of the media theories of Innis and McLuhan.
             6. Kevin Robins and Frank  Webster, “The Communications Revolution: New
           Media, Old Problems,” Communication 10, no.1 (1987): 72.
             7. Robins and Webster, “The Communications Revolution,” 72.
             8. Robins and Webster, “The Communications Revolution,” 72.
             9. Oscar H. Gandy, “Colloquy,” Critical Studies in Mass Communication 12, no.1
           (1995): 60.
            10. James W. Carey, “Abolishing the Old Spirit World,” Critical Studies in Mass
           Communication 12, no. 1 (1995): 82.
            11. Lawrence Grossberg, “Cultural Studies vs. Political Economy: Is Anybody
           Else Bored with this Debate?” Critical Studies in Mass Communication 12, no. 1
           (1995): 80.
            12. Janice Peck, “Why We Shouldn’t Be Bored with the Political Economy Versus
           Cultural Studies Debate,” Cultural Critique 64 (2006): 92.
            13. Richard E. Lee, Life and Times of Cultural Studies (Durham, NC: Duke Uni-
           versity Press, 2003), 2.
            14. Eileen R. Meehan, “Commodity, Culture, Common Sense: Media Research
           and Paradigm Dialogue,” The Journal of Media Economics 12, no. 22 (1999): 150.
            15. Jane Jacobs, Systems of Survival: A Dialogue on the Moral Foundations of
           Commerce and Politics (New York: Vintage, 1994).
            16. This possibility was raised by three of the four participants in the Colloquy.
           Carey and Grossberg maintained, however, that specialization is not just an explana-
           tion for the separation, but that it also provides justification for keeping the fields sep-
           arate. Murdock, representing political economy, dissented, urging that specialization
           needs to be overcome.
            17. Andrew Calabrese, “Toward a Political Economy of Culture,” in Toward a Po-
           litical Economy of Culture: Capitalism and Communication in the Twenty-First Cen-
   16   17   18   19   20   21   22   23   24   25   26