Page 111 - Critical Political Economy of the Media
P. 111

90  Critical investigations in political economy

             US newspapers in the late nineteenth century. There is no necessary connection
             between horizontal expansion and market concentration. However, when a firm
             attempts to secure as large a market share as possible the usual, ‘successful’ outcome
             is greater concentration. Vertical integration refers to the acquisition or control of
             companies in different stages of the ‘value chain’ leading from production to
             circulation, sales and consumption. Again, the process is not new. The Hollywood
             studio system in the 1920s is the classic example, notable also as a system dis-
             mantled in part through regulatory pressure when the US Supreme Court ruled in
             1948 that the studios must give up their exhibition operations, and then subse-
             quently reconstructed from the 1970s (Schatz 1997; Miller et al. 2005). However,
             vertical integration was a leading feature of changes in corporate organisation and
             business strategy from the 1980s. Older terms such as ‘diagonal’, ‘multisectoral’
             indicate patterns of integration across product sectors as firms diversify into new
             businesses, but such industry-based distinctions are becoming less tenable with
             accelerating convergence. All the major multimedia corporations are vertically
             and horizontally integrated and pursue diversification to occupy strategic posi-
             tions across platforms and services. BSkyB, part owned by 21st Century Fox,
             produces audiovisual content and sells ‘triple-play’ bundles of phone, TV and
             broadband subscriptions. Games companies such as Sony, EA and Nintendo
             have invested heavily in online and mobile platforms, and diversified revenues
             through micro sales transactions and advergaming (in-game advertising).

             Corporate synergy

             Achieving economies of scope has been another important driver of corporate
             merger activity. This took various forms including the integration of hardware
             manufacturers and software operations (Negus 1997). Another form was integration
             of telecoms and IT companies with media businesses involved in content creation,
             exemplified by the merger, but effectively acquisition, of Time Warner by AOL.
             Such economies usually arise ‘when there are some shared overheads or other
             efficiency gains available that make it more cost effective for two or more related
             products to be produced and sold jointly, rather than separately’ (Doyle 2002b:
             14). Savings can be made if the creative and other inputs gathered to make one
             product can be re-used in another (repurposing). In addition, product and brand
             extensions can increase the scope for profits. The Scandinavian Broadcasting
             System (SBS), for instance, cut production costs through the simultaneous
             production of a variety of programming formats targeted at different national
             markets (Iosifides et al. 2005: 84). The US-owned SBS broadcasting group,
             based in Luxembourg, has expanded from its Nordic market base and now
             controls channels in Northern and South-Eastern Europe. Firms use other means
             to achieve scope benefits including licences, alliances and joint agreements. Where
             first copy costs are high, there are incentives to sell the product or associated
             products in as many formats or ‘windows’ of opportunity as possible. This
             underlies the dynamics of branding and merchandising and the more recent
   106   107   108   109   110   111   112   113   114   115   116