Page 261 - Critical Dialogues in Cultural Studies
P. 261

ANGELA MCROBBIE 249

            decent and socially responsible (it never was), but as an expansive popular
            system’  (Hall,  1988:215,  quoted  in  McGuigan,  1992:38).  In  this  way  the
            market is opened up theoretically to incorporate some of the active cultural
            concerns  of  those  who  participate.  Contrary  to  this  position,  for  Clarke
            and  Pollert  the  market  remains  nothing  other  than  the  outcome  of  the
            process of accumulation. The market is ideological in that it suggests a field
            of choice and expression but in reality it is a determined space, the point at
            which  the  rate  of  profit  is  managed,  often  through  a  complex  set  of
            controls  and  manoeuvrings  involving  the  state  in  the  form  of  subsidies,
            investments  and  ‘welfare’,  all  of  which  are  means  of  ensuring  the
            sustainability of profits for capital. Clarke’s argument is that post-Fordism
            represents  little  more  than  a  strategy  developed  from  within  capital  for
            dealing with the falling rate of profit which the old interventionist state can
            no  longer  prop  up.  It  is  the  threat  to  profits  which  requires  capital  to
            reorganize itself along the lines of flexible specialization.
              In fact, between these writers there is less disagreement on post-Fordism
            emerging  from  the  crisis  of  capital  following  the  break-up  of  the  old
            postwar  settlement  than  they  themselves  seem  to  imagine.  It  is  more  a
            question of the political analysis which follows. Needless to say there is no
            mention of the word ‘culture’ in the Capital and Class writing. The nearest
            Clarke comes to engaging with what people might look for or find in the
            commodities of consumer capitalism lies in a fleeting reference to the old
            postwar  settlement  responding  to  ‘rising  working-class  aspirations’.  My
            point is precisely that the refusal to unpack the world of meanings in the
            idea  of  ‘rising  aspirations’  is  a  much  greater  flaw  in  the  otherwise
            sophisticated  arguments  of  both  Pollert  and  Clarke  than  the  difficult  and
            sometimes uncertain attempts by the New Times writers to revise orthodox
            left thinking on the market, to bring the economy back into cultural theory
            and at the same time to engage with the ‘politics of theory’, all in the space
            of an accessible and deliberately open-ended dialogue.
              The Capital and Class position in contrast means being left with capital
            lurching  from  one  crisis  to  another  but  always  with  a  set  of  strategies
            tucked  up  its  sleeve  for  further  exploiting  the  working  class  and  also  for
            pre-empting any possibility of class politics. It is here that ideology comes
            into  play.  It  manipulates  and  controls  the  working  classes,  end  of  story.
            (Capital and Class have little to say about women or black people and even
            less to say about cultural or identity-based politics.) This is in my mind a
            deeply anachronistic model. While no single account can hope to embrace
            the entire sweep of social changes which leave their mark across the whole
            landscape of everyday life, the real value of the New Times writers is that
            they  recognize  the  importance  of  understanding  social  change.  Thus  they
            take  the  emergence  of  new  forms  of  work  and  new  kinds  of  workers
            seriously.  This  is  the  first  account  for  example  to  acknowledge  the
            existence of substantial numbers of ‘design professionals’ whose job it is to
   256   257   258   259   260   261   262   263   264   265   266