Page 24 -
P. 24

INTRODUCTION   13

                            be moved around much like other resources such as money. Like other resources
                            the aim is to accumulate it and move it around for the good of the organization.
                            In short, more knowledge equals more profit. However, there is no particular
                            reason, a priori, why benefit should automatically follow from having more and
                            more knowledge. As seen with the widespread diffusion of e-mail, it is quite con-
                            ceivable that information overload might result and/or that existing, embedded
                            knowledge might constrain attempts to do new things. Thus knowledge, unlike
                            money, is not valuable in and of itself, but only where it is applied to specific tasks
                            (McDermott, 1999).
                              Another criticism of this approach is that it assumes a so-called ‘function-
                            alist’ view of organizations (Burrell and Morgan, 1979). In other words an
                            organization is depicted as a collection of interdependent parts (e.g. machines
                            and people) that work in harmony towards a common, agreed upon, goal –
                            (e.g. organizational survival and profit). However, this assumes that com-
                            mon goals actually exist in organizations and, therefore, does not address
                            important issues of power and conflict in organizations and in society at large
                            (Foucault, 1980). For example, encouraging individual employees to surren-
                            der their knowledge for the benefit of ‘the organization’ may actually ben-
                            efit shareholders or senior managers but can, equally, be for the individuals
                            themselves. This is one reason why individuals may choose to ‘hoard’ rather
                            than share knowledge. Moreover, it is quite conceivable that those in power
                            could use knowledge to further their own interests rather than the interests
                            of the collective organization.
                              As well as theoretical objections, there are some very practical issues when
                            it comes to using structural approaches to manage knowledge work. For one
                            thing, understanding types of knowledge (e.g. tacit/explicit) and where it
                            resides (e.g. individual/collective) does not actually tell us much about where it
                            comes from or how to use it – knowing, in this sense of the word, does not equal
                            doing (Pfeffer and Sutton, 2000). Furthermore, there is now good evidence
                            that Knowledge Management initiatives based solely on this kind of thinking
                            often fail (Walsham, 2002). For example, in an empirical study of an initiative to
                            encourage knowledge transfer in a world-wide bank, Newell et al. (2001) found
                            that the introduction of a Knowledge Management System – a global intranet –
                            designed to capture and share tacit knowledge across the organization had the
                            opposite effect to that intended by senior management. These problems will be
                            discussed further in Chapters 3 and 7.
                              These points of critique have led people to develop more sophisticated ‘con-
                            tingency’ frameworks that show us how strategies for managing knowledge can
                            be linked to specific aspects of the organizational tasks at hand. For example,
                            Hansen (1999) studied innovation in a large electronics company and concluded
                            that strong social relationships with a few people were beneficial for tasks that
                            required the transfer of complex, highly tacit knowledge, whereas weak rela-
                            tionships with many people were more effective where the knowledge involved
                            was less complex and more explicit. This approach is promising as it takes into
                            account purpose – that is what knowledge is to be used for. However it still,









                                                                                             6/5/09   6:56:37 AM
                  9780230_522015_02_cha01.indd   13                                          6/5/09   6:56:37 AM
                  9780230_522015_02_cha01.indd   13
   19   20   21   22   23   24   25   26   27   28   29