Page 102 - Key Words in Religion Media and Culture
P. 102

Economy  85

             consumption of wealth through the management of scarce resources and
             potentially  unlimited  needs.  However,  this  political  economy  could  also
             be subjected to critique, most notably by Marx and Engels, as a system of
             alienation that appropriated labor value as a surplus for satisfying the needs
             of a privileged social class.
               Both  of  these  approaches  to  political  economy—the  descriptive  and
             the  critical—differ  from  the  modern  science  of  economics,  which  bases
             its  calculations  on  the  notion  of  abstract  individuals  who  are  motivated
             by a desire for goods that are regulated by the pricing mechanisms of the
             market (Gregory 1982). However, all of these modern understandings of the
             economy, whether they focused on political order, contending social classes,
             or atomized individuals in a free market, all participated in what Max Weber
             identified as the modern differentiation of specialized social institutions. As a
             result, the economy could be regarded as a separate domain, which certainly
             affected any network of social relations but was in principle independent of
             other spheres of human activity such as religion or aesthetics.
               During  the  twentieth  century,  critical  theorists  of  political  economy
             challenged any privileging of the economic as a separate sphere. In a variety
             of critical interventions, accounts of economy that were developed embraced
             basically aesthetic categories of display and reciprocity in a gift economy
             (Mauss  1969),  of  excess,  extravagance,  and  sacrificial  loss  in  a  general
             economy (Bataille 1991), of desire in a libidinal economy (Lyotard 1993),
             and of representation, circulation, and interpretation in a symbolic economy
             (Goux 1990). In a dramatic and influential reevaluation of economy, Jean
             Baudrillard’s political economy of the sign proposed that late capitalism was
             essentially a signifying practice, circulating signs, rather than primarily a mode
             for producing material goods (Baudrillard 1981; 1994). As sociologists Scott
             Lash and John Urry argued, “What is increasingly being produced are not
             material objects, but signs” (Lash and Urry 1994: 5). Economy, therefore,
             was increasingly being recast as an economy of meaning.
               In  this  expanding  economy,  which  embraced  aesthetics,  desire,  and
             imagination  as  an  economy  of  signification,  the  aesthetics  of  cultural
             media, in all of its various forms, could also be rendered as an economy of
             production, circulation, and consumption. On the production side, during
             the 1930s the critical theorist Theodor Adorno called attention to the “culture
             industry,” the machinery of mass cultural production in a capitalist economy
             (Adorno 2001). As cultural production becomes an industry, the artwork is
             transformed into a commodity that is created and exchanged for profit. In
             the process, all cultural productions bear what Adorno called “the stigmata
             of capitalism” (Bloch et al. 1977: 123). In this production-oriented model,
             popular culture serves the interests of capital—profitability, uniformity, and
             utility—by entangling people in a culture industry in which a character such
   97   98   99   100   101   102   103   104   105   106   107